As
the heat and dust of the Indian elections settles down, as the BJP settles into
governing and as the Congress gets used to the idea of being out of power, it
might be possible to discuss the question asked in the title of this post. Before I start, I should state clearly what I
am not doing: I am not at all going
to suggest that the UPA should have been re-elected in the recent general
elections. Given its lacklustre performance, especially during the last two years
in office, and the various scams that took place, there is no denying that the
UPA deserved to be voted out. But the question in the title of the post is
important since it was one the major attacks against the previous government
(see here).
For a robust and general defence against that attack, I invite the reader to look
at the careful analysis of the UPA rule by Ghatak, Ghosh and Kotwal. My purpose in this post is far more limited: I want to narrowly focus on
the fiscal stimulus that was introduced by the UPA during 2008-09 and 2009-10
and show how this worked to protect India from the ravages of the Great
Recession. I am going to discuss this in the context of a branch of economics
known as Public Choice.
Public
choice tells us that a government often manipulates economic policy for
partisan objectives. One of its most important objectives is to remain in
office by being re-elected. This is a far more cynical view of governments as
compared to the textbook version which supposes that governments relentlessly promote
social welfare. Given the loss of innocence over the last few decades, I am
quite sure that the cynical view will find greater resonance among the
electorate than the standard textbook view.
Governments
have tremendous discretionary powers at their disposal, so that policies are often
crafted and implemented in such as manner as to enhance re-election prospects
of the party in power. Typically, a self-serving government will try and ensure
that the economy is doing well around the time of the elections. This is
expected to be done by introducing a public expenditure programme around
election time so that economic growth is healthy and unemployment is low. Inflation
inevitably follows in the wake of such a programme, but by that time elections
have already taken place and the ruling party is once again entrenched in power.
Policies to control inflation are now implemented and these lead to rising
unemployment. But this situation is non-threatening since the next elections
are far off. The middle of the electoral term is thus characterised by low
growth and high unemployment. As the next elections approach, once more the
economy is boosted to improve the chances of re-election.
Did
the performance of the UPA-II match the prediction of the public choice theory?
Not at all. It delivered high rates of growth in the two years immediately after
re-election: 8.2% and 8.9% in 2009-10 and 2010-11, respectively. Surprisingly,
this was higher than the 6.5% rate recorded in 2008-09, the year leading up to
the elections of 2009. Even worse for
UPA-II, it delivered its worst economic performance in the two years prior to
the elections of 2014. In short, its performance was the exact opposite to that
predicted by public choice theory.
The
question I address here is the following: if the UPA government were to behave
cynically, as proposed by public choice, how would it have behaved differently?
I am going to put forward a counterfactual narrative to the
events that unfolded from 2008-09 to 2011-12. Counterfactual history (interested
readers may check here)
is in the form of a “what if” question: what if the fiscal stimulus package were
not implemented in 2009-10?
This
counterfactual narrative will be compared to the factual narrative, which was
that India’s fiscal stimulus packages were activated on 7th December
2008, 2nd January 2009 and 24th February 2009. These actions,
which were in keeping with standard prescriptions for tackling recessions,
included excise duty cut, additional plan expenditure, increased government
borrowings, interest subsidies for export finance among other measures. The
increase in public expenditure due to this stimulus amounted to about 3 percent
of GDP (see Supriyo De).
It should also be remembered that the employment guarantee scheme (MNREGA) was
already in place by then which also added to public expenditures.
The
steps that I adopt to carry out the counterfactual exercise are given in the
appendix. In its essence, my counterfactual experiment seeks to estimate what
the GDP growth rate would have been if the fiscal stimulus of 2009-10 and
2010-11 had not taken place. The chart below gives the actual growth rate
of real GDP as compared to the counterfactual GDP growth rate derived from my
exercises.
The
figure makes clear that, in the absence of fiscal stimulus, Indian growth rate
would have faltered. From a public choice point of view, sacrificing growth
during 2009-10 and 2010-11, (with the government behaving as in the
counterfactual exercise) would have been the “rational” choice. Then, as the
elections of 2014 approached, a policy to stimulate the economy could have been
put in place. Of course, the point is moot whether it would have been possible
to revive the economy once it had lost its momentum. A very likely possibility
is that India would have slipped into a prolonged recession and extricating the
economy out of this would have required an even greater fiscal and monetary
stimulus with no guarantee of recovery. If that were to happen then, not only
would growth have remained low during 2012-13 and 2013-14, but possibly India
would have suffered sluggish growth right from 2009-10. This would have been no
different from the pattern of growth experienced in a large number of countries
which are still struggling to recover from the recession.
Considering
the growth performance of many countries around the world during the time
period 2008-09 onwards, it seems almost miraculous that India (and China) was
able to postpone the slowdown by a few years. See chart below:
The chart shows that, barring China and India, every
other country experienced negative growth rates in 2009 and positive but low rates
thereafter.
In fact, as the recession spread around the world, a
very large number of countries suffered very low rates of growth in 2009. See
chart below which has been created using World Bank data.
Out
of the 191 countries covered in the chart, 180 performed worse than India. Of
these, 90 had negative growth rates. This chart brings out sharply the
world-wide devastation wrought by the Great Recession. Of the 11 countries in
the top two groups (on the extreme right of the chart), excluding India and
China, the remaining 9 are very small countries with a combined population of only 151.1 million which is
less than 13% of India’s population. This probably gives a proper perspective
of the significance of India’s achievement during 2009-10 to 2011-12.
In
conclusion, I would like to propose the following two points:
- The ferocity of the recession was too great for any country, including India and China, to have escaped completely unscathed. That India was able to stave off its ill effects for three years is an achievement that is perhaps not adequately recognised and appreciated.
- The UPA-II government acted quite unlike the predictions put forward by public choice theory regarding self-seeking governments. In fact, by formulating and implementing a fiscal stimulus policy at the correct time, it acted sagaciously and unambiguously in the national interest. Far from having “destroyed” the economy, the UPA-II, in fact, protected the economy from the cataclysm that had engulfed the world.
APPENDIX
The
steps that I adopt to carry out the counterfactual exercise are the following:
- I consider two data series: GDP at constant prices and real Total (Centre + State) government expenditures.
- For the time period under consideration, I compute the expenditure multiplier defined as change in GDP divided by change in expenditure. I get values that are much higher than those reported in the literature (See Bose and Bhanumurthy). However, I continue to use my higher values. It may be noted that had I used the multipliers reported by Bose and Bhanumurthy, the counterfactual growth rate would have been even lower than the ones reported above.
- For the years 2008-09 to 2011-12, I create a counterfactual path of government expenditures using the average annual growth rate of the three years prior to 2008-09.
- The counterfactual path of government expenditures allows me to compute the changes in government expenditures which, when multiplied by the multiplier values of 2008-09 to 2011-12 (see step 2 above), gives me annual changes in real GDP.
- Finally, these changes in real GDP are used to create the counterfactual path of real GDP from which the counterfactual growth rates are extracted.
A great piece - intellectually very pleasing! I read this and decided to follow the author on g+ !
ReplyDeleteThe fiscal stimulus in 2009-10 was in continuation of the stimulus in 2008-09 which was a pre-election year. Was that stimulus in accordance with the predictions of public choice theory, given that it was in a situation of recession and it was not that a normal economy was pumped up for electoral gains, (though electoral gains there were in 2009, for sure, because of the stimulus)? Would it then not be necessary to continue this stimulus in 2009-10 to provide a sustained stimulus out of the slump. I agree that it would surely not be sagacious on the part of UPA-II if the stimulus had been withdrawn, but I think it would be giving too much of a credit to them to call them 'sagacious' if they continued the stimulus to pull the economy out of recession.
Not knowing much of Public choice theory, my real question is ''are the predictions of public choice theory as much applicable to an economy which is already in recession at election time or is it about initially creating a recession in post-election years in a normal economy to inflate it just prior to next elections?''
Hi Avadhoot,
DeleteThanks for reading the note and commenting on it. To answer some of your comments:
(a) By the time recession began (sometime around September 2008 with the collapse of Lehman Brothers), the budget for the year 2008-09 had already been passed. This included allocations for MNREGA which could well be seen as preparing for the elections of 2009. But the additional stimuli during Dec 2008 to Jan-Feb 2009 was in response to the recession. The stimulus continued in the next three years with rate of growth of govt expenditures of 14.6%, 14.7% and 16.1% before falling to 11.9% in 2012-13. Of course, since there was simultaneously a monetary stimulus, there followed the inevitable inflation which then had to be controlled. Interest rates were raised and then everything spiraled down.
(b) Public choice predictions of governments boosting the economy just before elections is independent of whether the economy is in recession or not. I have not come across recession-specific predictions of public choice. I do need to explore this.
I loved it! Reminded me of the time when I was doing my MBA during the economic crisis of 2008 and every day there would be a new event unfolding - atleast in the US. The collapse of Bear Sterns, Banks being bought out, America pumping money into the system - one of our very own Neel Kashkari (a Kashmiri and an UIUC alum) responsible for doling out TARP funds - every prof would take the latest event and describe it in the context of their subject - be it microeconomics, macroeconomics, accounting or even statistics (probability had suddenly become extremely relevant).
ReplyDeleteReading about this from a different perspective (for me) in India - the economic scene as well as the intense political / social / bureaucratic wrangling that transpired then - was very educating.
Ajit - I may not have said this before but you are our very own Paul Krugman - or our Greg Mankiw - not so much in terms of their political leaning - but the very strong conviction that is prevalent in your writing. Stimulus was then a contentious topic - and as Krugman believed then way more should have been pumped in the US...
Especially in the new political scenario in India it has become fashionable to beat up the incumbent- it is important to recognize and celebrate what was successful - that we are not a country that is simply a bystander in the economic waters - so to speak.
Hungry for more - especially your subtle (or not so sometimes) wit and the whole angle on counterfactual history.
Hey thanks for your comments. You flatter me by mentioning the name of Paul Krugman. But I do like Krugman writings though he sometimes gets to be a bit polemical. I have avoided that...so far!
Delete