Introduction
In a recent
public meeting, the Prime Minister (PM) of India stated, "Today in our
country, attempts are being made to collect votes by distributing free revdis
[an Indian sweet]".[i]
This statement of the PM has started a great debate on "freebies"
that are promised by political parties and financed out of public funds. The
issue is important and has a critical bearing on the public finances of the
central and state governments. It is, of course, moot whether this was the
appropriate way to initiate a serious discussion on controlling wasteful government
expenditures.
It is not
my intention to parse the PM's words and decipher the target of his barbs. I
want to explicate the issue of using public funds to provide goods/services for
the benefit of the country's people. It turns out that economics has a lot to
say about these issues and offers a critique of governments that misuse public
funds for partisan ends. A vast literature on clientelism[ii],
patronage,[iii]
and populism[iv]
views the provision of goods and services by the government as an exchange in
return for votes. Such quid pro quo with voters is, of course, frowned upon by
economists. Dani Rodrik notes in his paper on populism: "Economists
dislike populism, and for good reason. The term evokes irresponsible,
unsustainable policies that often end in disaster and hurt most the ordinary
people they purportedly aim to help".[v]
Economic
Rational for Government Intervention
Is there a
strong economic rationale for the government to provide goods and services to
the people? There is indeed one in a situation of market failure. The connotation of
market failure relevant here is a situation where the market does not supply
the required good or service (either at all or in adequate quantity) even
though there may be a strong demand for it. Market failure is most acute in
the context of pure public goods discussed in the Appendix below. The
category of goods implicated the most in the discussion on freebies is what Musgrave (1959)[vi]
called merit goods.
Merit Goods
Musgrave (1959) defines merit goods as
those goods which can be priced and provided by the market and yet the government provides additional quantities of such goods using
public funds. Kirchgassner (2014) notes that this description of merit goods
conflicts with the notion that individuals are best placed to judge what is in
their best interest and, hence, should be left free to decide for themselves. [vii]
But, he also points out that, in recent times, Behavioural Economics has
documented a variety of anomalies where individuals do not act in their own
interests.
The pricing of merit goods and the extent
of their availability are important issues. Recipients may receive a 100%
subsidy (i.e. a price of zero) or may have to pay a part of the price of the
good or service. Further, the availability of the good may be universal or may
be restricted based on specific criteria. Governments provide such a good/service if it:
Improves the welfare of the recipient: In the absence of the provision of the merit good, the welfare of
the recipient would fall below the minimum acceptable level.
Provides a social benefit to society: Even though the individual receives benefits from the merit good,
the society also benefits, e.g. basic education or basic health care, which is
often heavily subsidised.
It is
important to ask if the merit good should be universally available. For
example, till 1997, India's public distribution system was universally
accessible.[viii]
However, the oft-quoted remark of former PM, Rajiv Gandhi that only 15 paise of every rupee
meant for the poor reaches the intended beneficiary[ix]
led to a shift towards a better-targeted approach. The wasteful government
expenditure due to the inclusion of undeserving beneficiaries (either through
error or deliberately) in the coverage of merit goods gives urgency to the discussion
on freebies.
While much
of the recent discussion has focused on freebies from the expenditure side, it
is also important to consider tax revenues that are foregone, either on the grounds
of welfare or social benefit. Arguments have been made that (a) personal income
tax exemption limits should be increased to protect the welfare of the salaried
groups[x]
and (b) corporate income tax rates should be reduced to encourage corporates to
use the income so saved for capital expenditure which has a social benefit.[xi]
Votes-Merit Goods Quid Pro Quo
Standard
economy theory seems to believe that, even though individuals may maximise their
own welfare, these same individuals seek to maximise social welfare when they
form the government. The public choice approach points out this contradiction
and asserts that political parties will create policies to gain or retain power
in the next elections. Keeping the public choice approach in mind, I note that
(a) ruling political parties use public funds to provide merit goods to voters
in the hope of harvesting votes, and (b) challenger political parties promise
to provide merit goods if voted to power.
An
illustrative list of merit goods which satisfy the two reasons for their
provision – welfare of recipient and/or social benefit – is the following:
1. Subsidised or free education
2. Subsidised or free health services
3. Subsidised or free food
4. Free vaccination programmes
5. Ujwala Yojana for the provision of clean fuels (LPG)
6. Mid-day meal scheme for school children
How does
one judge whether the provision of these merit goods has the intended effect? For
example, the mid-day meal programme of Tamil Nadu was criticised for waste of
government resources by diverting resources from other better uses.[xii]
In short, the programme was criticised as a freebie. However, over the last few
decades, it has been recognised as an essential intervention in improving
nutrition and school enrollment. Likewise, the Ujwala Yojana may be criticised
for not permanently weaning away households from traditional fuels which have an
adverse impact on health (mainly of women) but can anyone challenge the welfare
objectives of the scheme? [xiii]
Does the
provision of such merit goods yield political dividends to the ruling political
party or a challenger party that promises such goods? A large amount of
literature in this area has supported the view that economic factors influence
voters.[xiv]
Deshpande and others did find that voters rewarded the BJP for their welfare
schemes, especially in the areas where the party was already strong.[xv]
Whether
voters reward political parties that promise them merit goods is a complex
question that I do not explore here. Whatever the answer to that question, political parties will seek to
exploit this possibility if they believe they may get even the slightest
advantage from making such promises. Beyond promises of merit goods, political
parties have also sought to attract votes by distributing sarees[xvi]
and colour TVs.[xvii]
How does one estimate what proportion of expenditure on goods and services provided
by central and state governments has been on genuine merit goods and on
freebies (i.e. goods which have neither a welfare dimension nor a social
benefit dimension)? To the freebies component must also be added the
expenditure incurred by deliberately including undeserving beneficiaries in the
distribution of merit goods.
Given the
power to provide merit goods, the decision-making of political parties can also
be influenced by lobbying. Special interest and lobbies will try to coax the
ruling party to provide them with goods which may not have the qualities of merit
goods or lobby to get cuts in tax rates.[xviii]
It should be evident that, as the provision of merit goods and tax breaks
expand, there is increasing stress on the government's public finances.
Conclusion
Apart from
the political fireworks that have erupted from the revdi swipe by the
Prime Minister, the critical question is whether the problem of excessive
promises of merit goods can be solved outside the sphere of politics and
economics. From an economics point of view, the issue is clearly one of fiscal
sustainability. An indiscriminate expansion of expenditure on undeserving merit
goods may reduce the fiscal space available to the government and may crowd out
other more essential expenditures. However, India has developed institutional
mechanisms (albeit imperfect ones) to control irresponsible spending by governments. Fiscal
Responsibility Legislation, passed by both central and state governments in
India, is an important mechanism to usher in fiscal discipline.[xix]
This legislation imposes limits on central and state governments' debt as well
as on their deficits. In addition, the recommendations of the various Finance
Commissions provide one more check on the fiscal performance of central and
state governments.[xx]
For instance, the Fifteenth Finance Commission's Report recommends grants to
states based on specific performance indicators while also recommending limits
on levels of debt and deficits.[xxi]
[xxii]
Beyond the
institutional controls that may be imposed on governments, the voice of the
electorate should be the most important, whereby governments are rewarded or
punished based on their performance. A political party that makes bombastic,
non-credible promises to the voters will lose its credibility in the electoral
market, while a party that delivers on its promises will gain the trust of the
voters. After all, this is an essential function of elections. I
write this bearing in mind that elections are not necessarily won or lost based
on a rational evaluation of performance and that ideological factors may also
play a significant role. Bryan Kaplan notes that voters are often irrational
and sometimes selectively so: "We habitually tune out unwanted information
on subjects we don't care about" (p.2).[xxiii]
Hence, voters might be forgiving of a political party that matches their
ideology, and they may turn a blind eye to its poor performance.
The PIL
currently being heard in the Supreme Court in connection with freebies is a
dead end, given that it might be impossible to define a freebie or distinguish
it from a merit good. A Supreme Court judgement deciding what governments can
or cannot spend on will play havoc with the democratic system in
India. It will tie the hands of governments for the foreseeable future and
reduce the flexibility and discretion that may be critical for policy
formulation. Imagine the Indian government wasting precious resources and time
trying to convince the judiciary that free vaccination against COVID was not a
freebie! Any intervention by the Supreme Court on this issue will constitute
extreme judicial overreach.
APPENDIX
Pure
Public Goods
The
category of goods known as pure public goods must be provided by the government
even in the most capitalist economies. The presence of public goods leads to
complete market failure, and the supply of such goods will be zero if left to
the market. Why is this so? Two qualities characterise a pure public good:[xxiv]
Non-rivalness in consumption: More than one person can consume the same unit of a good at the
same point of time. For example, numerous persons can stand under a street light
and receive its benefits at the same point time. The good is not depleted or
exhausted in the process of consumption
Non-exclusion: It is impossible or very costly to exclude individuals from consuming a good even if they do not pay. Imagine getting individuals to pay for a street light every time they pass under it. Exclusion may be costly in some cases: you need turnstiles and ticket-checkers to prevent individuals from using the train services without paying for them.
When both of these qualities are present, no individual consumer will have an incentive to volunteer payment for the good; hence, no private producer can cover the cost of providing such goods.[xxv] In such cases, the government must provide these goods. Please note that a distinction is being made between producing a good and providing it. The classic example of a pure public good is defence services. But, even in this case, private producers may produce the defence equipment that is sold to the government, which, in turn, provides defence services to the people. Obviously, such goods cannot be termed as freebies or revdis. A political party that does not commit to providing such goods will severely compromise the welfare of its people. A complex question I do not explore is how the government decides how much of the public good to provide.[xxvi]
[i] Express News Service (2022) PM slams freebie politics: Revdi
culture dangerous, need to end it, https://indianexpress.com/article/cities/lucknow/pm-slams-freebie-politics-revdi-culture-dangerous-need-to-end-it-8034057/
[ii] Pranab Bardhan and Dileep Mookerjee (2016) https://edi.opml.co.uk/wpcms/wp-content/uploads/2018/07/EDI-PF-PAPER-10.III_.5-Bardhan-and-Mookherjee-1.pdf
[iii] Naseemullah
(2021) https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/pdf/10.1080/14662043.2021.1910397
[iv] Dani Rodrik
(2018) Is Populism Necessarily Bad Economics?, AEA Papers and Proceedings 2018,
108: 196–199, https://scholar.harvard.edu/files/dani-rodrik/files/is_populism_necessarily_bad_economics.pdf
[v] Dani Rodrik
(2018), page 196.
[vi] Musgrave R.A. (1959) The theory of public finance : a study in
public economy, McGraw-Hill, New York
[vii] Kirchgassner,
G. (2014) Soft Paternalism, Merit Goods, and Normative Individualism, https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/96867/1/cesifo_wp4688.pdf
[viii] Swati
Narayan (2021) Time for Universal Public Distribution System: Food Mountains
and Pandemic Hunger in India, Indian Journal of Human Development, https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/full/10.1177/09737030211049007
[ix] Press Trust
of India (2017) ‘Only 15 paise reaches the needy’: SC quotes Rajiv Gandhi in
its Aadhaar verdict, Hindustan Times, https://www.hindustantimes.com/india-news/only-15-paise-reaches-the-needy-sc-quotes-rajiv-gandhi-in-its-aadhaar-verdict/story-I8dniDGXF6ksulggTDgb9L.html
[x] Rituraj
Baruah (2022) Increase in income tax exemption limit among top expectations
from Budget: KPMG, Live Mint, https://www.livemint.com/budget/news/increase-in-income-tax-exemption-limit-among-top-expectations-from-budget-kpmg-11642780834832.html
[xi] Aditya
Murlidharan and Prasanna Tantri (2022) Corporate tax cuts do boost investments,
Hindu Business Line, https://www.thehindubusinessline.com/opinion/corporate-tax-cuts-do-boost-investments/article64938246.ece
[xii] Padmini Swaminathan, J.
Jeyaranjan, R. Sreenivasan and K. Jayashree (2004) Tamil Nadu's Midday Meal
Scheme: Where Assumed Benefits Score over Hard Data, Economic and Political
Weekly , Oct. 30 - Nov. 5, 2004, Vol. 39, No. 44 (Oct. 30 - Nov. 5, 2004), pp.
4811-4821, https://www.jstor.org/stable/4415741#metadata_info_tab_contents
[xiii] Abhishek
Mishra (2022) Ujjwala scheme beneficiaries in UP resort to old cooking methods
as LPG prices skyrocket, India Today, https://www.indiatoday.in/india/story/ujjwala-scheme-beneficiaries-up-old-cooking-methods-lpg-prices-skyrocket-1972948-2022-07-07
[xiv] Gebhard Kirchgässner (2016) : Voting and Popularity, CESifo Working
Paper, No. 6182, Center for Economic Studies and ifo Institute (CESifo),
Munich, https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/149269/1/cesifo1_wp6182.pdf
[xv] Rajeshwari Deshpande, Louise Tillin, and KK Kailash (2019) The
BJP’s Welfare Schemes: Did They Make a Difference in the 2019 Elections?
Studies in Indian Politics. 2019;7(2):219-233, https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/abs/10.1177/2321023019874911
[xvi] Ashish
Pandey (2014) EC says no to Bathukamma saree distribution in Telangana, India
Today, https://www.indiatoday.in/india/story/trs-kcr-bathukamma-saree-distribution-scheme-telangana-ec-congress-1355877-2018-10-04
[xvii] PTI (2011) EC
orders stoppage of free colour TV distribution in TN, The Hindu, https://www.thehindu.com/news/national/tamil-nadu/EC-orders-stoppage-of-free-colour-TV-distribution-in-TN/article14944523.ece
[xviii] See Mancur
Olson (1971) Logic of Collective Action, Harvard University Press, Harvard
[xix] PRS Legislative Research (2017) Report Summary – FRBM Review
Committee, https://prsindia.org/files/policy/policy_committee_reports/1493207354_FRBM%20Review%20Committee%20Report%20Summary.pdf
[xx] Finance
Commission (undated) Finance Commissions – A Historical Perspective, https://fincomindia.nic.in/ShowContent.aspx?uid1=2&uid2=1&uid3=0&uid4=0&uid5=0&uid6=0&uid7=0
[xxi] Finance
Commission (2020) Finance Commission in COVID Times: Report for 2021-26, https://fincomindia.nic.in/ShowContent.aspx?uid1=3&uid2=0&uid3=0&uid4=0&uid5=0&uid6=0&uid7=0
[xxii] PRS
Legislative Research (2021) Report of the 15th Finance Commission for 2021-26, https://prsindia.org/policy/report-summaries/report-15th-finance-commission-2021-26
[xxiii] Bryan
Kaplan (2007) The Myth of the Rational Voter, Princeton University Press,
Princeton
[xxiv] Julian Reiss (2021) Public Goods", The Stanford Encyclopedia
of Philosophy (Fall 2021 Edition), Edward N. Zalta (ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2021/entries/public-goods/
[xxv] The two qualities of pure public goods mentioned above
need not be present at the same time and this gives rise to a variety of goods
as detailed in the table below:
Characteristics |
Rivalness in
Consumption |
Non-rivalness in
Consumption |
Exclusion |
Private Goods
(e.g. ice cream, masala dosa) |
Club goods
(Fitness centre, train/plane journey) |
Non-exclusion |
Common resource
stock (e.g. groundwater, fish stock) |
Pure public good
(e.g. defence services, street lights) |
[xxvi] Dennis Mueller (2014) Public Choice, Social Choice, and Political Economy, https://crem-doc.univ-rennes1.fr/wp/2014/2014-03-ccr.pdf. Mueller provides a discussion of a variety of mechanisms that may be used to determine the quantity of public goods.
Ajit, I deferred the understanding of public economics to you in our non-autonomous Department in the last century. Musgrave still fills me with dread. My ignoramus response to your tight, nuanced essay is as follows. Both in absolute terms and terms relative to our neighbours, we are deficient in primary education and health facilities. The task, we now realise, is not just expenditure but fruitful delivery in the form of committed and well-paid teachers ensuring that young, open minds imbibe the fundamentals of the sciences and social studies. Basic Health, likewise, is a proactive and preventive business. However, considerations here quickly lead to the provision of nutritious food, clean water, and the boundaries of the subject get vague. Mind you, it is not a matter of the outlays getting unbounded. The government budget constraint partakes too much of the logic of the private budget constraint for my comfort. You and I are constrained by “fiscal space”. That term smacks of a given and I don’t understand it as applying to a government. Thus, a progressive income tax, a wealth tax, an inheritance tax, have independent merits and are not the wherewithal to ‘finance’ government expenditures. I am not a fan of ‘market failures’ because I am not persuaded by the vulgar notion of markets on which they are founded. Markets are products of history as are caring and interventionist states.
ReplyDeleteComing to the nub of your post, if any of the above is instituted the payoffs will be realised well beyond the five-year horizons of incumbent governments.
Thank you for your comments, Romar. As usual you provide much food for thought. There is much that I agree with you especially about the problems with delivery of education and health. Much more needs to be done beyond just the availability of government funds and that is where the real challenge begins. If the New York Times story is to be believed and Delhi schools have indeed become much better, then someone (Manish Sisodia?) needed to spend days and weeks and months ensuring that the funds are utilised well. Where is one to find that commitment and how does one replicate it across India? There are also some great success stories that Bannerjee and Dufflo narrate (in 'Poor Economics') about institutional changes that bring about wonderful transformation. The problem, as usual, is large-scale replicability of these solutions.
ReplyDeleteI use the term 'fiscal space' as the ability of the government to discharge its responsibilities given some budget constraints. I probably differ with you on the notion of budget constraint. While the constraint is definitely not as tight as it is for private individuals, it cannot expand indfefintely (without some costs being incurred). I have used the term fiscal space to mean the points that I have just made. I have been reading up the literature on fiscal space but I find that there is far too much diversity in the way the term is used and there isn't a clear way of measuring it. But, in a loose sense, I think the term conveys what I have written above.
Finally, I also differ with you on the notion of markets and market failure. I see markets as an institution that has important instrumental value in the allocation of resources. Conversely, I have much suspicion of any overbearing role that governments may play even though in some situations only governments can perform certain functions (some of which I have mentioned in the post).
Thank you once again for your comments.
HI Ajit: I liked your timely discussion on the topic of freebies. I also agree with you on your conclusion that the intervention of the SC on this issue is unwarranted on both constitutional grounds ( fiscal independence of state governments) and simple commonsense grounds such as definitions of freebies etc. It may be useful to also explore the role of "freebies" that are primarily directed for single period/current consumption versus "freebies" that are legitimately investments (bicycles, laptops etc.) which might also help accumulate human capital. I also think that there is always the option in a democracy of voting out irresponsible governments if they fail to deliver a higher quality of life i.e. if populism is unsustainable, the perpetrators will probably get voted out. Granted they may have done massive damage to the economy and other institutions.
ReplyDeleteThat wasn't a wondrous situation. When you are not strong, you should be smart. I understand?easier said than done. Skin Care is an unpopular arrangement to complete Skin Rejuvenation. You can hire experts to discover this news for you.
ReplyDeletehttps://www.salubritymd.com/
https://sites.google.com/view/hydroserum-ocean-shake/
https://www.salubritymd.com/chemist-warehouse-keto-gummies/
ReplyDeletehttps://www.salubritymd.com/
https://sites.google.com/view/hydroserum-ocean-shake/
ReplyDeletehttps://www.salubritymd.com/hyaluronan-crema/
https://sites.google.com/d/1BuQQ0AZl4PatYYpm8o9-6b0WevsQdoGR/p/1-c2w5CsSyNxRlT3BDc_d3vN1N86RKt7k/edit
Certain approaches in alternative medicine claim to remove "toxins" from the body through herbal, electrical or electromagnetic treatments. These toxins are undefined and have no scientific basis, making the validity of such techniques questionable. There is little evidence for toxic accumulation in these cases, as the liver and kidneys automatically detoxify and excrete many toxic materials including metabolic wastes.
ReplyDeletehttps://www.offerplox.com/weight-loss/belly-blast-keto-gummies/
https://www.offerplox.com/weight-loss/active-keto-gummies/
https://www.offerplox.com/cbd-products/blissful-aura-cbd-gummies/
https://www.offerplox.com/skin-care/clean-as-teen-skin-tag-remover/
https://www.offerplox.com/weight-loss/summer-body-keto-acv-gummies/
https://usanewsindependent.com/2023/11/belly-blast-keto-gummies-scam-update-keto-acv-belly-blaster-reviews-kelly-clarkson-2023-weight-loss-gummies/
https://usanewsindependent.com/2023/11/green-farms-cbd-gummies-hidden-truth-500mg-full-spectrum-gummies-for-pain-stress-aaron-rodgers-cbd-for-anxiety-works/